• Municipal Economic Enterprises vs. State Economic Enterprises: A New Arena for Employment Patronage?

    Ahmet OĞUZ, Aslı TAŞBAŞI, Yeşim Pınar SOYKUT SARICA

    Orcid ID: 0000-0001-7561-2405

    Orcid ID: 0000-0001-8349-607X

    Orcid ID: 0000-0002-9640-8582

     

    Abstract: State Economic Enterprises (SEEs) have been going through a privatization process, which began in the 1980s, increasing its pace since the 2000s. Against this trend, some argue that Municipal Economic Enterprises (MEEs) are being used to create employment with populist policy intentions in recent years. These argument rests on the perception that the MEEs have replaced the SEEs in using employment as an instrument for populist policies. The purpose of this study is to compare the populist policies during the years 2003-2015 which mark the timeline that privatization took speed, by means of the employment provided through the municipality in contrast to the employment policies of the previous governments, realized through SEEs. Theoretical approach of the study is based on Gramsci’s theory of hegemony, which includes the key concepts of patronage, clientelism and social state. Research findings within the limitation of data unavailability suggest that, MEEs do not have a significant potential for populist policies by means of employment patronage. On the other hand, since MEEs manage their operations by means of outsourcing, subcontracting and tenders to private sector companies, one can suggest that there is a potential clientelism relation between them and their service providers. 

    Kamu İktisadi Teşebbüslerine karşı Belediye İktisadi İşletmeleri: Patronaja Dayalı İstihdam için Yeni bir Alan mı?Keywords: Municipal Economic Enterprises, State Economic Enterprises, employment, patronage, clientelism.

    Öz: Kamu İktisadi Teşebbüsleri (KİT) 1980'lerde başlayan ve 2000'li yıllardan itibaren hızını arttıran bir özelleştirme sürecinden geçmektedir. Öte yandan, Belediye Ekonomik İşletmeleri’nin (Bİİ) de popülist politika hedefleri ekseninde istihdam yaratma amaçlı kullanıldığına dair tartışmalar ortaya çıkmış bulunmaktadır. Söz konusu tartışmalar, Bİİ'nin popülist politikalar için bir araç olarak istihdamın kullanımında KİT’lerin yerini aldığı yönündeki kanıya dayanmaktadır. Bu çalışmanın başlıca amacı, özelleştirmenin hız kazandığı bir zaman çizelgesinde, 2006-2015 yılları arasında, belediyeler tarafından sağlanan istihdam ile önceki hükümetlerin KİT’ler üzerinden yürütülen istihdam politikalarının karşılaştırılmasıdır. Çalışmanın teorik yaklaşımı, patronaj, kliyentalizm ve sosyal devlet kavramlarını kapsayan Gramsci’nin Hegemonya Teorisi’ne dayanmaktadır. Konuyla ilgili verilere erişim sınırlılığı çerçevesinde araştırma bulguları, Bİİ'lerin, istihdama dayalı patronaj yoluyla popülist politikalar için önemli bir potansiyele sahip olmadığını göstermektedir. Diğer taraftan Bİİ, faaliyetlerini dış kaynak kullanımı, taşeronluk ve özel sektör şirketlerine ihale yoluyla yönettiğinden, kendileriyle hizmet sağlayıcıları arasında potansiyel bir kliyentalizm ilişkisi olabileceği düşünülebilir.

    Anahtar Kelimeler: Belediye İktisadi İşletmeleri, Kamu İktisadi Teşebbüsleri, istihdam, patronaj, kliyentalizm.

    Introduction

    Since the early days of the Turkish Republic, the governments have been criticized for their populist policies through the employment function of the State Economic Enterprises (SEEs) with a view to create hegemony over the crowds. Although there are several tools used by the political parties for this purpose, employment created through the SEEs was the most salient method in the eyes of the public.

    There is a wide range of research available on the employment and management of SEEs as well as their historical development and privatization process and the so called “financial burden” created on the State through them. SEEs in Turkey have been going through a privatization process, which began in the 1980s; increasing its pace since the 2000s. Particularly after the 2003 general elections in Turkey, a rapid privatization process with the SEEs was followed, thus a powerful tool to generate employment patronage was lost.

     

    Since the MEEs were out of the audit of the Turkish Court of Accounts (Sayıştay) under the law no: 6085 defining the audit area of Sayıştay was amended to cover the MEEs (Küçük: 2015), arguments over the MEEs being used for populist policies were widely accepted. Some argue that MEEs are used to generate employment with populist policy intentions (Meşe, 2011). This creates a perception that MEEs have replaced SEEs in using employment as an instrument for populist policies.

    In order to investigate the presence of such a possible patronage effect, the main goal in this paper is to look into the development of historical employment data of SEEs and the employment data available on MEEs with a view to compare the findings to see if there is a relation with the selected local and general election years in Turkey. The remainder of the paper is as follows. The second part presents the theoretical setting. Part three provides a background where the employment processes of the SEEs and the MEEs are explained. Part four presents the analysis with its basic assumptions and looks behind the data. Part five concludes.

    Theoretical Framework

    Gramsci developed the concept of hegemony, which originally was used by Lenin as a term in establishing an analysis of how the ruling capitalist class creates and maintains its control in developing a Marxist State concept. Gramsci (1971) defines the state as the ruling class hegemony seeking to obtain the consent of the people under its ruling. The ruling class creates hegemony through the society, by ruling through the State’s exercising and legal power (Carnoy, 2001). Consent of the crowds is crucial for the establishment of the hegemony and without this consent hegemony cannot be established.

    Without consent, the only instrument to rule the people would be using physical force. History is full of examples of rulings established by force, which never lasted for long. Therefore, consent of the masses is essential for the political parties in a democratic system to be elected to form the government, thus achieving the ruling power of the State. Governments seeking to obtain the consent of the people to create hegemony should create a “positive image”. That is, the voters should be convinced that the politicians, and the political party they belong to will be acting in line with the expectations of the voters in economic, social and political policies during their ruling period. Adjustments in the taxation system, establishing amicable investment and business environment, providing favorable health care and both financial and social support (distributing food, coal and similar financial and non-financial items such as employment in state entities) to the crowds are some of the advantages which can be provided to the voters. The “exchange of votes and advantages” creates a “patronage” relation between the voters and the politicians.

     

    While Key (1964) states that “patronage may be considered as the response of government to the demands of an interest group – the party machinery – that desires a particular policy in the distribution of public jobs”, Sorauf (1960) defines patronage as “an incentive system – a political currency with which to ‘purchase’ political activity and political responses”, and Lande (1973) suggests patronage can be described as “supportive exchange dyads” in which patron and client exchange services mutually beneficial. The term “patronage” finds one of its best coverage in Weingrod’s (1968) article with the indication that the term appeared with increased frequency in anthropological analysis in 1960s, further stating that it is observed in the relations between “patrons and clients”. In this context the term “patron” is used for the person who uses his influence to provide help and protection to someone who later becomes the “client” in return to providing certain services for his patron. It can be said that “patronage” is the complex of relations between those who use their influence, social position or some other attribute to assist and protect others and those when they so help and protect (Boissevain, 1966).

    Campbell (1964) states that “the structure of the system of patronage, which is based on social relationships between clients seeking for a man with the ability and friendship connections to protect them and a patron who accepts these duties in return for political allegiance, growing upwards and through lawyers, other persons of influence, and members of parliament linked to the legislative assembly. Thus, the organization of government and the structure of patronage are parallel hierarchies”. Meanwhile Mayer (1966) defines the mutually beneficial relation between the patron and the client as follows: “In patronage, the transactor (patron) has the power to give some benefit which the respondent (client) desires… Examples of this would be the improvement of a road near the respondent’s house, or the employment of the respondent (or their relatives) in an office over which the (patron) has control.” Favoring their relatives or people politically connected to them (nepotism) are widely observed in the history of the Turkish Republic. Like nepotism, favoritism can appear in various ways, such as arranging financial incentives through state banks, providing employment within state enterprises or other state employment schemes, tax reductions, land allocations, etc.

    Metin (2011: 182 -183) states that clientelism is a result of the patronage relation, which goes back to Ancient Rome that sprouts out from inequality and poverty. Therefore, the relation is inclined to repeat itself. Clientelist policies define the social policies of the ruling party since the party would like to continue its “reign”, thus it has to align its policies with the “clients”.

    Citizens vote for politicians, who they assume would act to the best of their interest and politicians try to get the votes of the citizens to get elected, thus creating a mutually beneficial cycle. This relationship cycle opens a door on each side establishing a patronage and clientelism relation. The voters may prioritize their short-term interests and disregard the-long term benefits of the society in general. Construction of “slum houses” on government property by the farmers facing accommodation problem after immigrating to big cities in masses (due to the increasing mechanization in farming from the late 1940s) in Turkey is one example to this issue.

    Memişoğlu and Durgun, (2007) argue that, employment appears to be the easiest tool that can be used to create the patronage relation. Citizens seeking employment in a high unemployment economy may naturally vote for a politician or the political party promising rapid and favorable employment opportunities. For politicians, the most convenient way to fulfill this promise is using state enterprises or entities disregarding the basic rules of economy such as supply and demand, efficiency, while understating the long-term effects of inefficient employment. The research question of this paper rests on this very idea and further investigates whether MEEs have replaced SEEs in this way of recruiting personnel according to party clientele commitments.

    Background: The SEEs, the MEEs and the Take Over

    The SEEs were originally established with the purpose of economic development in the 1930s, yet they were also used for populist policies to create employment hegemony by the politicians. Therefore, they were subject to significant changes in their employment levels. The total number of employees in the SEEs increased from 7,331 in 1938 to 653,066 in 1985 (Gülmez, 1973: 33).

    Among the categories of employment in the SEEs, the civil servants on one hand were one of the most affected groups with a decrease of 97.46%, from 187,276 in 1985 to 4,085 in 2019. On the other hand, the number of contracted workers increased from 4,159 in 1985 to 132,421 in 1988 just in three years and reached the highest level of 188,880 in 1999, which eventually fell to 44,256 in 2019. These fluctuations represented an increase of 4,441.48% between 1985 and 1999, and a decrease of 76.57% by 2019. The change in the number of the workers under a union decreased from 385,547 to 47, 394 by 87.71% between 1985-2019. While non-union workers did not exist in 1985, their number reached 3,493 in 2019 (see Table 1). However, while analyzing the number of union membership numbers, one should keep in mind that the reliability of this data is questionable since there is a serious gap between the actual situation and the official figures (Çelik and Lordoğlu, 2006: 23).

     


    [1]  Işık Üniversitesi, Sosyal Bilimler Enstitüsü, Çağdaş Yönetim Doktora Programı

    [2]  Doç. Dr. Işık Üniversitesi, İktisadi ve idari Bilimler Fakültesi, İşletme Bölümü

    [3]  Doç. Dr. Işık Üniversitesi, İktisadi ve idari Bilimler Fakültesi, Ekonomi Bölümü

    Makale Geliş Tarihi:24.10.2019, Makale kabul Tarihi:14.05.2020

    Table 1: Employment in the SEEs (1985-2019)

    Years

    Civil Servants

    % Total

    Contracted Workers

    % Total

    Workers (Union)

    % Total

    Workers (Non-union)

    % Total

    Temporary Workers

    % Total

    Total

    1985

    187,276

    28.68

    4,159

    0.64

    385,547

    59.04

    0

    0.00

    76,084

    11.65

    653,066

    1988

    78,652

    12.02

    132,421

    20.23

    331,877

    50.70

    38,493

    5.88

    73,131

    11.17

    654,574

    1990

    27,074

    4.21

    185,083

    28.78

    349,053

    54.28

    8,810

    1.37

    73,038

    11.36

    643,058

    1993

    16,428

    2.74

    188,880

    31.52

    307,599

    51.33

    7,362

    1.23

    78,975

    13.18

    599,244

    1995

    13,085

    2.64

    165,074

    33.26

    231,812

    46.70

    6,782

    1.37

    79,599

    16.04

    496,352

    1998

    11,667

    2.55

    164,537

    36.00

    195,206

    42.71

    6,979

    1.53

    78,705

    17.22

    457,094

    2000

    10,329

    2.38

    141,801

    32.62

    182,793

    42.05

    16,891

    3.89

    82,841

    19.06

    434,655

    2005

    7,012

    2.84

    86,870

    35.13

    119,900

    48.49

    4,033

    1.63

    29,447

    11.91

    247,262

    2010

    6,307

    3.39

    78,813

    42.34

    90,241

    48.48

    2,950

    1.58

    7,826

    4.20

    186,137

    2015

    4,431

    3.71

    46,118

    38.61

    59,031

    49.42

    3,758

    3.15

    6,114

    5.12

    119,452

    2019

    4,085

    4.06

    44,256

    44.02

    47,394

    47.14

    3,493

    3.47

    1,307

    1.30

    100,535

    Source: Republic of Turkey Ministry of Treasury and Finance, https://www.hmb.gov.tr 

    One can assume that the decrease in the number of the employees in all categories was due to the privatization of the SEEs and thus the decrease in their total number. However, when looked closer at these figures according to their share in the total number of employees, it can be seen that, while the share of civil servants in the total SEEs decreased from 28.68% in 1985 to 4.06% in 2019, the share of contracted workers increased from 0.64% in 1985 to 44.02% in 2019 presenting a significant increase in contract-based workers. During the same period, the share of the unionized workers decreased from 59.04% to 47.14%, while the share of the non-union workers reached 3.47%. SEEs reached highest-ever employment in 1987 with 660,837 employees.

    Looking at the financial performance of the SEEs, they continuously created budgetary deficits until 1987, which decreased between 1987- 1989, and starting from 1990, their spending increased while their profit was going down (Murat, 2012: 100). Continuous “losses” of SEEs and their “burden” on the State budget increased the voices against them. The neoliberal policies imposed on Turkey through different channels, such as the ones by the International Monetary Fund (IMF), were the catalyst in creating a lobby supporting privatization of SEEs, which found more supporters over time. In 1965, the US announced that the financial aids provided to Turkey would be stopped by 1973. Prime Minister Süleyman Demirel’s speech indicating that “the West did not want Turkey’s industrialization” (Övgün, 2005: 68) presents the real reason behind the privatization efforts. Although there used to be an intention for privatization of the SEEs since the Republic was founded, nothing concrete was done until 1986 when the Law no: 3291 setting a framework for the privatization of the SEEs was accepted (Murat, 2012: 117; Övgün, 2005: 65). Eventually, methods such as partial payments through Istanbul Stock Exchange (ISE), and block sale of the shares to both domestic and international investors were used during the privatization of the SEEs.

    In this environment where the employment patronage by the SEEs is essentially blocked by major privatization movements, MEEs evolved to be active in many fields. According to Berk (2003), municipalities establish economic enterprises to carry out various functions such as providing water, gas, transportation; provision of basic needs which are not undertaken fully or partially by the State or SEEs (bread, meat, sugar etc.); establishing monopolies; local development projects aimed at dealing with the capital inadequacy in the region (managing spring resorts, weaving plants etc.); provision of water, gas, transportation for the residents of a city, and may create local monopolies while carrying out these services. He further suggests that Municipalities may also seek to create new income resources through managing car park, business center, hotels etc. and while carrying all these services and activities they may also create employment to the members and supporters of the political party they belong to, which can be considered clientelism and employment hegemony creation, falling within the scope of this study. This wide range of activities enabled the municipalities not only spend outside the supervision of the central government, but also employing high profile staff to manage these businesses, providing higher salaries which cannot be available within the state personnel salary scale. MEEs are places where politics are highly visible, widely used for political employment purposes as well as for actual needs to provide services (Meşe, 2011).

    So how does the employment process take place in the MEEs? Municipalities in Turkey apply the officially designated so called norm cadre system like the central government. Maintaining certain qualification requirements is compulsory for initial employment. According to Adıgüzel (2011), municipalities apply three types of personnel system. Similar to the central and local management, these systems are i. The Combined System, ii. The Separate Personnel System and iii. The Mixed System respectively.

    In the Combined System; the central and local personnel form one single personnel system where transfers between the two units are possible. Here, establishment of the cadre setting up the number of the workers to be employed and starting contractual employment is permitted under the consultation of the central government (Karahanoğulları, 1988: 288).

    In the Separate Personnel System; the central and local government employees are separated which implies that the Municipal personnel system is managed independently from the central government (Eken and Şen, 2005:109). Local management has the power to define the number of the employees to be hired and initiate employment without consulting the central government (Karahanoğullari, 1988: 283). Eken and Şen (2005: 109) state that the third system is the “mixed system” which finds its place between the two prior systems and the staff is directly employed by the municipalities. However, the personnel policies are directed and controlled by the central government. They further foresee the “Separate System” is replacing the “Combined System”, which was the preferred system since the establishment of the Republic

    Municipal Economic Enterprises (MEEs), are corporations with independent budgets either fully or partially owned by the municipalities to carry out some local services. Article 70 of Municipality Law no 5393 and article 26 of Metropolitan Municipality Law no: 5216 provide the legal environment for the municipalities to establish companies within the framework of their line of business and authority (Meşe, 2011). MEEs are instrumental for hiring people with higher wages. Since they are not under State Personnel Regime, mayors can freely employ whoever they prefer, and establish complete control and ruling over these enterprises within the constraints of the municipal council which itself may be under the mayor’s influence.

     

    The Analysis

    Basic Assumptions and the Setting: Conservative Islamists and Employment in the MEEs

    Neoliberal municipal concept in Turkey was first introduced during the Motherland Party (MP) in early 1980s right after the military coup of 1980. Neoliberalism was the new economic doctrine in the world and Turkey, changing economic policies from import substitution to neoliberal policies, which dictated the withdrawal of state intervention, i.e. implementing liberal economies thus increasing the weight and priority of the private sector.

    Implementation of neoliberal policies in municipalities were initially seen in major cities such as Istanbul, Ankara and İzmir, where some of the functions of the municipalities were separated from the municipality and provided through Municipal Economic Enterprises established, such as in transportation, electricity and water distribution.

    As Doğan (2011) states, Social Democrat People’s Party (SDPP) tried to smooth the effect of neoliberal approach of Motherland Party, between 1989 and 1994, when it was able to win in some big and medium sized cities. Establishment of Halk Ekmek and building a dealer network in the cities, allocation of cheap land and providing infrastructure and licensing facilities for housing cooperatives, increasing the salaries of the municipality employees, facilitating the infrastructure needs of the slum houses built in the cities were all approaches to strengthen the social aspects of the municipalities, which were negatively affected by previous policies (Doğan, 2011: 60-61). Doğan (2011: 61) further argues that SDPP also had an attitude change and inclined towards neoliberal policies and started to implement policies parallel to the requests of local and international capital, such as applying tenders and subcontracting some businesses of the municipality.

    Beginning with the WP, the approach to the management of municipalities changed seriously. Beyaz Masalar (White Tables) was established targeting to decrease the bureaucracy involved. The mayors had weekly meetings in a different neighborhood, in gatherings named as “Public Assembly” (Doğan, 2011: 63), which fits perfectly with the clientelism concept.

    JDP, having seen the success of WP and VP, pursued their neoliberal policies and inherited the idea of building close relations with the public through the social aid activities such as distributing clothing, coal, providing health care to the poor and paying regular visits to their homes more intensively. 

    JDP also pursued the neoliberal economic policies of previous governments persistently creating a strong hegemony over the social and political life, as well as the work life and the unions (Çelik, 2017: 192). It considered the municipalities strategically important to create and widen its hegemony over the voters with socio-cultural policies, as well as through the capital groups such as the Independent Industrialists and Businessmen Association (Müstakil Sanayici ve İşadamları Derneği – MÜSİAD) and the Businessmen and Industrialists Confederation of Turkey (Türkiye İşadamları ve Sanayicileri Konfederasyonu – TUSKON, the business association which is shut down in 2016 for its alleged financial support to Fethullah Terrorist Organization - FETO) by helping to improve them financially (Doğan, 2009: 115). Tendering municipal businesses to private sector companies through the MEEs helped the development of financial relations with the mentioned capital groups. Speaking of Istanbul Metropolitan Municipality, establishment of the MEEs such as Kültür A.Ş., Sağlık A.Ş., Spor A.Ş. and İSMEK (which provides numerous courses to district residents) are examples for the involvement of the municipalities in the socio-cultural lives of the individual voters. 

    JDP, continued with the neoliberal policies inherited from WP and VP, having seen the success of them, distributing clothing, coal, providing health care to the poor and visiting their homes more intensively. Following the 2002 elections JDP focused on providing more independence and power to municipalities under the “Local Administrations Reform” program.

    Following the 2002 elections JDP focused on providing more independence and power to municipalities under the “Local Administrations Reform” program. Municipality and metropolitan municipality laws issued in 2004-2005 (Law no: 5216 and 5393) should be considered as steps taken towards this goal. According to neoliberal policies JDP was following, municipalities being at the center of local managements should downsize the employment figures as well as the weight of central government. Municipalities should be empowered and their functions should be carried out by the private sector. The best way to realize this was establishing the MEEs and outsourcing the needed activities to the private sector through the MEEs by tenders.

    The following section presents the data and the relevant implications. As a basic assumption, in the analysis of the votes, Welfare Party (WP), Virtue Party (VP) and Justice and Development Party (JDP) as “Islamist Conservatives” have been considered the continuation of each other, and further assumed to have the same ideology including leadership. Indeed, some of the ministers and the leaders of today’s JDP were in the ranks of WP and VP previously. Party leaders constantly put an emphasis on the public in their speeches and statements. Table 2 and 3 show the results of the local elections presenting the increase in the votes of WP, VP and JDP as well as the municipalities won. The success of WP, VP and JDP in consecutive local elections was the key opening the door to the victory of general elections of 2003 for JDP. Social policies towards the same marginalized layers of the society increased intensively in this election (Akdoğan, 2009: 210). Sparking a successful patronage relation leading to increased success in municipal elections leading to a success in the general elections (Buğra, 2002: 189).

     

     

    Table 2: Local election results for WP, VP and JDP for Metropolitan Municipalities

    Total Number of Metropolitan Municipalities

    Municipalities Gained

    Total Votes Received

    Vote %

    1989 (WP)

    8

    1

    464,9

    9.03

    1994 (WP)

    15

    6

    2,048,494

    22.4

    1999 (VP)

    15

    4

    2,438,076

    23.36

    2004 (JDP)

    16

    12

    4,822,636

    46.06

    2009(JDP)

    16

    10

    7,672,280

    42.19

    2014(JDP)

    30

    18

    15,898,025

    45.54

    2019(JDP)

    30

    16

    13,158,693

    47.96

    Source: Supreme Election Council (1989-2019).

    http://www.ysk.gov.tr/tr/mahalli-idareler-genel-secimleri-arsivi/2650

     

    Table 3: Local Election Results of WP, VP and JDP for Municipalities

    Total Number of Municipalities

    Municipalities gained

    Total votes received

    Vote %

    1989 (WP)

    1,976

    73

    1,174,454

    8.73

    1994 (WP)

    2,695

    323

    3,784,419

    19.06

    1999 (VP)

    3,2

    484

    4,301,538

    18.40

    2004 (JDP)

    3,209

    1,753

    9,690,538

    40.16

    2009(JDP)

    2,903

    1,442

    12,449,187

    38.64

    2014(JDP)

    1,351

    800

    17,952,504

    43.13

    2019(JDP)

    1355

    742

    18,368,421

    42.55

    Source: http://www.ysk.gov.tr/tr/mahalli-idareler-genel-secimleri-arsivi/2650/ http://www.ysk.gov.tr/tr/mahalli-idareler-genel-secimleri-arsivi/2650

     

    Looking behind the Data

    Seeking a relation between the employment figures of municipalities and elections is one of goals of the analysis adopted in this paper. Limitations on data availability created some setbacks; yet, the data collected is sufficient to at least have an insight on the existence of such a relation. Election years which have been taken into consideration in the paper are 1999, 2002, 2007, 2011, 2015, 2018 for the general elections and 1999, 2004, 2009, 2014, and 2019 for the local elections.

    For the analysis of the available data we will be looking for increases during the election years and decreases in the following years to make an assumption on the existence of employment hegemony. In the beginning of the period (end of 1996) the total number of civil servants were 95,139, which decreased to 76,517 at the end of 2006, however started to increase the following year and despite some fluctuations reached to 106,629 by March 2020 (see Table 4).

    Looking at the employment figures of civil servants one can observe an increase in the general election years of 1999, 2002, 2015, and local election years of 1999, 2004, 2009 and 2019 followed by a decrease the next year. No significant change is observed for the general election years of 2002, 2007, 2009, 2011, 2018.

    The only change in the employment of contracted employees took place in the election years of 2002, 2004, 2009 and no fluctuation has been observed for the remaining election years. However, changes for all election years have been observed (except 2007 and 2019) election years for employment figures of workers. On the other hand, a significant increase has been observed in ‘temporary worker” Figure 2 for the election year of 2007 and a decrease in the following year. Similar changes are observed in ‘temporary workers’ figures for the election years of 1999, 2004, 2009, 2011, 2014 and 2018, even though for some election years this fluctuation can be considered insignificant.

    Table 4: Employment Figures of Municipalities and MEEs in Turkey, 1996-2019

     

    Municipalities and Related Entities

    Municipal Economic Enterprises

     

     

    Civil Servants

    Contracted Employees

    Workers

    Temporary Workers

    Other

    Total

    Civil Servants

    Contracted Employees

    Workers

    Temporary Workers

    Other

    Total

    Grand Total

    1996

    95,139

    994

    94,050

    73,761

    N.A.

    263,944

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    1997

    96,479

    1,276

    90,018

    82,911

    N.A.

    270,684

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    1998

    98,734

    706

    89,561

    93,995

    N.A.

    282,996

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    1999

    95,182

    735

    83,460

    97,151

    N.A.

    276,528

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    2000

    89,501

    1,054

    74,301

    94,977

    N.A.

    259,833

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    2001

    88,408

    1,267

    71,578

    100,152

    N.A.

    261,405

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    2002

    91,397

    1,204

    70,644

    100,439

    N.A.

    263,684

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    2003

    83,835

    1,078

    59,025

    114,265

    N.A.

    258,203

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    2004

    83,309

    1,310

    63,182

    123,182

    N.A.

    270,983

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    2005

    80,541

    1,013

    57,312

    106,843

    N.A.

    245,709

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    2006

    76,517

    3,440

    49,176

    112,259

    N.A.

    241,392

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    2007

    81,673

    5,648

    76,807

    98,522

    4,059

    266,709

    8,965

    11

    3,538

    554

    8,023

    21,091

    287,800

    2008

    81,649

    8,252

    121,191

    52,548

    6

    263,646

    8,740

    50

    4,028

    377

     

    13,195

    276,841

    2009

    78,431

    21,705

    143,294

    10,098

    10,433

    263,961

    8,340

    97

    2,781

    403

    15

    11,636

    275,597

    2010

    81,727

    12,364

    142,071

    9,139

    2,812

    248,113

    10,099

    331

    4,202

    847

    8,177

    23,656

    271,769

    2011

    82,611

    16,193

    111,134

    7,256

    5,507

    222,701

    10,132

    451

    3,799

    1,006

    6,653

    22,041

    244,742

    2012

    83,610

    19,856

    103,051

    7,177

    6,762

    220,456

    11,481

    436

    4,922

    1,616

    5,285

    23,740

    244,196

    2013

    107,612

    2,753

    101,415

    9,810

    N.A.

    221,590

    4,462

    1,188

    11,445

    2,883

    N.A.

    19,978

    241,568

    2014

    119,064

    4,408

    108,190

    7,008

    N.A.

    238,670

    4,668

    1,242

    11,972

    3,016

    N.A.

    20,898

    259,568

    2015

    111,587

    9,777

    86,894

    6,017

    N.A.

    214,275

    6,547

    1,743

    16,793

    4,230

    N.A.

    29,313

    243,588

    2016

    109,583

    13,189

    79,973

    5,717

    N.A.

    208,462

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    90,270

    N.A.

    90,270

    298,732

    2017

    109,556

    14,078

    78,257

    5,807

    N.A.

    207,698

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    99,871

    N.A.

    99,871

    307,569

    2018

    102,205

    15,886

    73,194

    7,695

    N.A.

    198,980

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    339,717

    N.A.

    339,717

    538,697

    2019

    105,012

    19,751

    66,182

    4,417

    N.A.

    195,362

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    475,039

    N.A.

    475,039

    670,401

    2020 (March)

    106,629

    20,134

    67,494

    4,476

    N.A.

    198,733

    N.A.

    N.A.

    N.A.

    496,388

    N.A.

    496,388

    695,121

    Source: Republic of Turkey Presidential Strategy and Budget Directorate, http://www.sbb.gov.tr/kamu-istihdami/

    Note: Graphical representation of Table 4 is provided with Figures 1 and 2.

     

    Figure 1: Employment Data of Municipalities and Related Entities (MEEs excluded) 1996-2006

    img1 

     

    2007-2019

    img2 

    Source: Based on data presented in Table 4.

     

    No employment data was available for the pre-2007 period for the MEEs. Analysis of the available data collected on MEEs show some fluctuations between 2007-2015, which cannot be considered significant for denoting populist. However, starting from 2015 all employment realized as ‘temporary workers’ presents significant increases every year until 2020 from 90,270 in 2015 to 496,388 in 2020.

    A meaningful analysis could not be carried out for the “other” category, which took place between 2007-2012 since detailed information on this title could not be gathered, for both data groups (Municipalities & related entities and the MEEs).

     

    Figure 2: Employment in the MEEs

    img3 

    Source: Elaboration based on, Republic of Turkey Presidential Strategy and Budget Directorate

     

    Examining the employment figures presents striking information on the employment tendency in the municipalities. In 1999 where a general and a local election took place, there was no significant change in the number of the employees. However while the number of the workers directly employed decreased by 6,101 representing a decrease of 6.81%, the number of temporary workers increased by 3,156 representing an increase of 3.36%. As of 2013 (Q3), the total number of the employees at MEEs is 8,780, thus representing 7.28% of the employment at the municipalities.

    Total spending of the municipalities between 2006 and 2012 increased by 117.13%. In the same period the personnel expenses increased by 72.22%, while employment increased by 12.83%. Personnel expenses in 2006 comprised 22% of the total spending at the municipalities. This ratio was realized as 17% at the end of 2012 and 7.9% at the end of 2017 in line with the decrease in the number of employees (See Table 5).

     

     

    Table 5: Total Spending and Personnel Expenses of Municipalities and MEEs Compared

     

     

    2006

    2007

    2008

    2009

    2010

    2011

    2012

    2013

    2016

    2017

    2018

    Municipalities

    Total Spending (000)

     

    21,640

     

    25,833

     

    30,959

     

    31,048

     

    34,475

     

    41,133

     

    46,988

     

    59,964

     

    91,270

     

    112,048

     

    132,005

    Personnel Expenses (000)

     

    4,769

     

    5,073

     

    5,945

     

    6,430

     

    6,961

     

    7,579

     

    8,213

     

    9,084

     

    12,290

     

    12,917

     

    14,717

    % of Personnel Expenses to Total Expenses

     

     22.04

     

    19.64

     

    19.2

     

    20.71

     

    20.19

     

    18.43

     

    17.48

     

    15.15

     

    13.47

     

    11.53

     

    11.15

    Source: Republic of Turkey Ministry of Interior, General Directorate of Local Administrations, Local Administrations General Activity Report

     

    Conclusion and Implications for Further Research

    This paper provides a first attempt_ to the best of our knowledge_ in investigating whether the MEEs are used as a new patronage arena through employment as in the SEEs before privatizations in Turkey. The available data handled in the study show that the MEEs do not have a significant potential given their employment levels, for populist policies via employment patronage. On the other hand, since the MEEs manage their operations by means of outsourcing, subcontracting and tenders to private sector companies, one can assume that there is a potential clientelism relation between them and their service providers, as well as the possibility that the employment patronage might be carried out through them.

    Although there has been no change in the functions of the municipalities and on the contrary they increased by type and volume in line with the population increase and developments in the cities, as relevant data portrays, the functions of the municipalities are increasingly carried out by service providers, which causes a decline in the direct employment requirements. This suggests that neoliberal policies may have a significant effect on the employment structure of not only the State Economic Enterprises but the Municipalities as well. The fluctuations in the employment figures of Municipalities during election times also suggest that there is an employment hegemony in Municipalities. However, a detailed analysis on the Municipalities with more detailed employment data (monthly, quarterly) has to be carried out to reach a certain conclusion.

    The employment data points that there is a need for further research to be carried out on the causes of the fluctuations in the municipalities’ employment figures for temporary workers. The data for MEEs’ employment of temporary workers is only available for the years after 2006. Starting from this year, number of temporary workers employed in the MMEs increased continuously, in particular, a rapid increase is observed between 2015 and 2020. One can argue that the increase in the employment of temporary workers can be an indication of populist employment initiatives.

    The relevant data show that the SEEs intensively used contract-based employees between 1988-2000, reaching to a peak in 1995, which decreased dramatically by 75 per cent from this level in 2019. Although one may suggest that the decrease in the total number may be linked to the decrease in the number of SEEs due to privatization, the percent shares of the contracted and temporary workers imply that the SEEs increasingly used them as the preferred employment method which should also be considered as an area open to patronage hegemony and clientelism relation and further analysis.

    Looking at the budget figures, a fluctuation in the personnel expenses is also observed between the years 2006 – 2017. This point also has to be analyzed by means of the expenditure items. There has been no shrinkage in the functional areas of the municipalities, but a serious decrease is observed in the number of the employees, accompanied with increased total budget spending. This can only be explained by outsourcing facilities.

    Since the data on the topic is such limited that this limitedness strongly influences the findings and the conclusion of the paper, what is to be stated should go beyond the data. As a consequence of promises made prior to elections in local administrations there is indeed a visible increase in employment volumes following municipal elections. This signals the role of “clientelism and patronage systems”, but this trend may not be so well-entrenched and long- term in MEEs as was once the case in the SEEs in Turkey. It can be argued that, in response to pressures for cost-saving concerns, there also seem to be attempts for lay-offs following election times.

    There may also arise unanticipated problems hindering the smooth operation of ‘clientelism’; especially where the newly- elected mayor and members of the city council (policy making organ) may turn out to belong to apposing political parties (as was the case in the recent 23rd of June 2019 Istanbul local elections), where the management of the newly mayor may be curbed by the opposing city council. For example, of the MEE managers may refuse to lose their positions earned prior to the new election.

    As regards to preferences for hiring different employee categories (e.g. workers vs. civil servants subcontracted employees or temporary workers), the trend in the public sector has been towards employing more flexible worker types, e.g. temporary workers and especially subcontracted labors in Turkey. Civil servants enjoy stronger job security, but weaker collective bargaining rights compared to workers in general, and for these reasons the public employers (municipalities) seem to prefer hiring those categories more often. In response to lamentations by subcontracted labors for their below- standard working conditions, the government has had to convent most of them into permanent worker positions. Yet the actual implementation of this policy has not been satisfactory either as there were inconsistencies in their actual wage payments. As for union rights, workers and the union movement aspire for more equal treatment between these categories, (e.g. representation of subcontracted labors by the same union if they are employed in the same establishment doing work similar to the work of permanent workers).

    All in all, we can conclude by saying that the analysis adopted in this paper was unfortunately surrounded by a major problem of data unavailability. Despite this constraint, there are essential implications that can be derived from the paper as summarized above. We believe that these implications may at least pave the way for future research, which is hopefully going to be based on transparent data publicly open.

     

     

    REFERENCES

    Adıgüzel, M. (2011) “Belediyelerde Personel Sistemi ve Uygulaması”, Dış Denetim Dergisi, 4.

    Akdoğan N. S. (2009) “Secularism & Islamism in Turkey”, M.A. Mohamed Salih (ed.) Interpreting Islamic Political Parties, New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 207-230.

    Berk, A. (2003) “Yerel Hizmet Sunumu ve Belediye İktisadi Teşebbüsleri”. Sayıştay Dergisi, 49, 47-63.

    Boissevain, J. (1966) “Patronage in Sicily. Royal Anthropological Institute of Great Britain and Ireland, Man”, New Series, 1:1, 18-33.

    Buğra, A. (2012) “Labour, Capital, and Religion: Harmony and Conflict among the Constituency of Political Islam in Turkey”, Middle Eastern Studies, 38: 2, 187- 204.

    Campbell, J. (1964) Honour, Family and Patronage, Oxford: Clarendon Press. 

    Carnoy, M. (2001) “Gramsci ve Devlet”, Praksis, 3, 252-278.

    Çelik, A. (2017) “AKP Döneminde Sendikal Haklar: Sendikasız-Grevsiz Kaynaşmış bir Kitleyiz”, in M. Koray and A. Çelik (ed.) Himmet, Fıtrat, Piyasa, İstanbul: İletişim Yayınları: 157-193.

    Çelik, A. and Lordoğlu, K. (2006) “Türkiye’de Resmi Sendikalaşma İstatistiklerinin Sorunları”, Çalışma ve Toplum, 9, pp. 53-59.

    Doğan, A. E. (2011) “1994’ten Bugüne Neoliberal İslamcı Belediyecilikte Süreklilik ve Değişimler.”, Praksis 26: 2, 55-75.

    Doğan, A. E. (2009) “29 Mart 2009 Seçimleri ve AKP: Türkiye’nin Siyasal Coğrafyası Açısından Bir Değerlendirme”, Praksis, 21:3, 113-134.

    Eken, M. And Şen, M. L. (2005) Belediye Personel Sistemi ve Son Gelişmeler, Yerel Yönetimler Üzerine Güncel Yazılar-I, Ankara: Nobel Yayın-Dağıtım.

    Gramsci, A. (1971) Selections from the Prison Notebooks. New York: International Publishers.

    Gülmez, M. (1973) “Türk Kamu Görevlilerinin Sayısal Evrimi”, Amme İdaresi Dergisi, 6,:1, 25-39.

    Karahanoğulları, O. (1998) “Belediye Personelinin Hukuki Yapısına İlişkin Gözlemler”, Ankara Üniversitesi Hukuk Fakültesi Dergisi, 47: 1-4.

    Key, V.O. (1964) Politics, Parties and Pressure Groups, New York: Thomas Y. Crowell.

    Küçük, H. (2015) “Türkiye’de Belediye Şirketlerinin Denetimi Üzerine Bir Değerlendirme”, Journal of International Management, Educational and Economics Perspectives, 3(1), 39-52.

    Lande, C.H. (1973) “Networks and Groups in Southeast Asia: Some Observations on the Group Theory of Politics”, American Political Science Review, 67:1, 103 – 27.

    Mayer, A. (1966) “Quasi-Groups in the Study of Complex Societies”, in M. Banton (ed.), The Social Anthropology of Complex Societies, New York:Frederick A. Praeger, 19, 113–114.

    Memişoğlu, D. And Durgun, A. (2007) “Devlet Başarısızlığına Yol Açan Etkenlerden Biri Olarak Patronaj İlişkileri”, Yerel Siyaset, 27 Dec. retrieved from: http://www.yerelsiyaset.com.

    Meşe, M. (2011) “Belediye Şirketleri Üzerine Bir Değerlendirme”, Dış Denetim Dergisi, 4, 203-215.

    Metin, O. (2011) “Sosyal Politika Açısından AKP Dönemi: Sosyal Yardım Alanında Yaşananlar”, Çalışma ve Toplum, 1, 179-200.

    Murat, S. (2012) “İstihdam Açısından Kit’ler ve Özelleştirilmeleri.”, İstanbul Üniversitesi, Sosyal Siyaset Konferansları Dergisi, 97-131.

    Övgün, B. (2005) “Geçmişten Günümüze Kamu İktisadi Teşebbüsleri.”, Genel-İş Emek Araştırma Dergisi, 1, 65- 83.

    Republic of Turkey Prime Ministry Under secretariat of Treasury, General Directorate of State Economic Entities and Enterprises. (2011) 2010 State Economic Entities Report, Ankara.

    Republic of Turkey Ministry of Treasury and Finance. “Number of Employees of State Owned Enterprises”. https://www.hmb.gov.tr (13.05.2020)

    Republic of Turkey Ministry of Interior, General Directorate of Local Administrations, (2006) 2005 Local Administrations General Activity Report, Ankara.

    Republic of Turkey Ministry of Interior, General Directorate of Local Administrations, (2009) 2008 Local Administrations General Activity Report, Ankara.

    Republic of Turkey Ministry of Interior, General Directorate of Local Administrations, (2010) 2009 Local Administrations General Activity Report, Ankara.

    Republic of Turkey Ministry of Interior, General Directorate of Local Administrations, (2012) 2011 Local Administrations General Activity Report, Ankara.

    Republic of Turkey Ministry of Interior, General Directorate of Local Administrations, (2017) 2016 Local Administrations General Activity Report, Ankara.

    Republic of Turkey Presidential Strategy and Budget Directorate. http://www.sbb.gov.tr/kamu-istihdami/ (13.05.2020).

    Sorauf, F.J. (1960) “The Silent Revolution in Patronage”, Public Administration Review, 20.

    Supreme Election Council. Mahalli İdareler Genel Seçimleri Arşivi. http://www.ysk.gov.tr/tr/mahalli-idareler-genel-secimleri-arsivi/2650 (13.05.2020).

    Weingrod, A. (1968) “Patrons, Patronage, and Political Parties”, Comparative Studies in Society and History, 10: 4, 377-400.

© 2019 - ÇALIŞMA VE TOPLUM DERGİSİ